Banner Advertiser

Monday, February 9, 2009

[ALOCHONA] 75 politicians cleared of graft charges

75 politicians cleared of graft charges
Courtesy New Age 10/2/09

The Anti-Corruption Commission has cleared 340 people, including 75 politicians, of corruption charges pressed against them in December 2008 and January 2009, ACC spokesman Hanif Iqbal told reporters at a news briefing on Monday.
   Hanif, also ACC director general (admin), said the commission had lodged 208 cases against the 340 accused persons on charge of misappropriating relief materials, receiving bribes, embezzling state money, causing loss to national exchequer, amassing illegal wealth and laundering money.
   Sixty-six government officials and 188 people from other professions are among the 340 people accused during the military-controlled interim regime.
   According to the commission’s statement, it cleared 277 persons in 176 corruption cases in December 2008 while the rest were cleared in January.
   Of the politicians, eleven are from BNP, three from Awami Leauge, three from Bangladesh Jamaat-e-Islami and 58 others are chairmen or counsellor from the BNP and AL, said the commission statement mentioned.
   Former BNP ministers Tariqul Islam and Asadul Habib Dulu, who were accused in separate iron-sheet misappropriation cases, and former minister Aminul Huq, who was accused in embezzlement case, were cleared of the charges.
   Seven former BNP lawmakers — Nasiruddin Ahmed Pintu of Dhaka, Shah Mohamamd Abu Jafar of Faridpur, AKM Selim Reza Habib of Pabna, AKM Fazlul Haque Milon of Gazipur, Abul Hossain Khan of Barisal, Shamsudduha Khan of Naogaon and MA Mannan of Gazipur, all accused in misappropriating corrugated iron-sheet cases, and another former BNP lawmaker Md Gias Uddin of Narayanganj accused in three cases relating to cheating and embezzlement, were cleared of the charges.
   Two former Jamaat lawmakers — Abdus Sobhan of Pabna and Gazi Nazrul Islam of Satkhira, both accused in iron-sheet misappropriation cases, and another former Jamaat lawmaker Abdullah Mohamamd Abu Taher of Comilla, accused in relief wheat embezzlement case, were cleared of the charges.
   Agriculture minister Matia Chowdhury, accused in wheat embezzlement case in 2002, Chittagong mayor ABM Mohiuddin Chowdhury, accused in three cases relating to fund embezzlement, businessman Salman F Rahman, accused in a case for embezzling Tk 191.39 crore of the fund of Arab Bangladesh Bank, were among the Awami League men cleared of the charges.

 




__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] False statement of Education Minister

In a meeting with visiting Indian Foreign Minister, our education minister said the following:
"India helped us during our independce struggle. (A true statement). India continued to help us after independence. ( A false statement)." - The daily Ittefaq. Feb 10, 2009
What the education minister could have told the Indian foreign minister "India helped us during our independce struggle. But it continued to screw us after the independence. (A true statement)". To support his statement, he could bring the following issues ( I am surprised none of our ministers including the PM brought the following issues):
1. Farakkah (No. 1 reason for flood in Bangladesh).
2. Push in the poor Indians to Bangladesh.
3. Improper tarrifs on Bangladeshi products.
4. BSF killings.
 



__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] Re: [Dahuk]: JS probe into DGFI excesses : Right Demand

Recent probe against DGFI was raised by corrupt figures such Mohiuddin Alamgir, Abdul Jalil and a few others. Intelligence agencies play a vital role in every societies. Bangladesh needs to have this kind of agencies to keep an eye out for the corrupts. DGFI played crucial role in 1/11 which stopped the nuisances created by politicians. If there was no 1/11, there wouldn't be a JS ruled by AL. It is the direct action of military and DGFI which brought the level playing field in the general election. Our politicians are champions in making mistakes and if they make the mistake of taking action against DGFI, then when we will really need someone to intervence we wouldn't have them.
I am really surprised that someone who was sentenced 13 years, gets out of jail and shouts in parliament. We need to find out where the rules of the land is. How can a convict be in the parliament, is that because his party in power? Please send him where he belongs.

 
 

--- On Mon, 2/9/09, S A Hannan <sahannan@sonarbangladesh.com> wrote:
From: S A Hannan <sahannan@sonarbangladesh.com>
Subject: [Dahuk]: JS probe into DGFI excesses : Right Demand
To: dahuk@yahoogroups.com, islamcity@yahoogroups.com, mukto-mona@yahoogroups.com, sahannan@yahoogroups.com, sonarbangladesh@yahoogroups.com
Date: Monday, February 9, 2009, 9:54 PM

 JS probe into DGFI
excesses
: Right Demand

Daily New Age has reported that Workers Party president Rashed Khan Menon Sunday demanded a parliamentary investigation into the excesses done by the military intelligence during the two years' rule of the interim administration.
   'Parliament needs to investigate the excesses in order to stop their recurrence once and for all,' Menon said while speaking on a thanks giving motion on the presidential address delivered in parliament on January 25. Menon drew a parallel between the activities of the Inter-Service Intelligence of Pakistan and
Bangladesh's military intelligence agency, Directorate General of the Forces Intelligence, saying the DGFI had spied on the media through its information wing while it controlled politics through its political wing. 'My question is whether Bangladesh has turned into Pakistan,' he said adding that the terms of reference of the DGFI stipulate that it would provide intelligence information for political authorities. 'But the DGFI tried to control politics and politicians during that period, they tried to create a king's party. They prevented the 14-party alliance leader Sheikh Hasina from returning home from abroad, they tried to split political parties and create misunderstanding among party leaders in the name of reforms,' Menon said.   Menon termed the Fakhruddin Ahmed-led caretaker government a military-controlled administration .They suspended fundamental rights and tens of thousands of people were evicted from their homes in the name of drives against illegal occupation. As many as 4,000,000 poor people were deprived of their earnings He also said the interim government had launched a drive against politicians in the name of anti-corruption drive and did not differentiate between corrupt elements and politicians. 'They also tried to implement the so-called 'minus two' theory to keep the two top leaders away from politics.
   Referring to law minister Shafique Ahmed's statement that the immediate past government was a doctrine of necessity, the WP leader said that the question of giving legitimacy to this government did not arise. 'We can forgive, but we cannot validate the activities of the military-backed government.' He said the repetition was not expected. 'I demand a parliamentary committee to investigate the actions also of the military-backed government to stop its recurrence.'He called on the new government to be vigilant that national interest was not harmed while going for agreements with foreign companies for exploration and extraction of mineral resources.
We support the statement of Mr. Menon in essence .The Jatiya Sangshad ( Parliament ) should enquire into all extra-legal activities of the past government.The illegal political activitied of DGDFI should be stopped for ever. Mr Menon has mentioned about only ISI, he could also mention CIA, KGB,RAW, MOSSAD.In fact there is need for an international awareness and/or  protocol as regards the role of spy agencies.
   

 




__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

Re: [ALOCHONA] EC sues minister for violating electoral code of conduct

Now is the right time for PM Hasina to show her support against corruption. Surprisingly, no action has been taken against this minister and a few other MPs who broke the law. If the PM is really willing to fight the corruption, this is where she should start. PM needs to fire the minister and force those culprit MPs to resign, inaction from her side proves her love towards corruption.
 


--- On Sun, 2/8/09, Ezajur Rahman <ezajur.rahman@q8.com> wrote:
From: Ezajur Rahman <ezajur.rahman@q8.com>
Subject: [ALOCHONA] EC sues minister for violating electoral code of conduct
To: alochona@yahoogroups.com
Date: Sunday, February 8, 2009, 12:52 AM

EC sues minister for violating electoral code of conduct
New Age 8/2/09 Staff Correspondent

The Election Commission on Thursday filed a case against the fisheries and livestock minister, Abdul Latif Biswas, his daughter and four other local Awami League leaders for intervening in polling and violating the electoral code of conduct in the upazila elections.
   The commission in the case alleged Latif had assaulted polling personnel, snatched ballot papers and captured polling centres at Belkuchi in Sirajganj.
   Nitish Chandra Dey, district election officer 1 of Sirajganj, lodged the case on the commission's behalf with the 'Kha' region of the additional chief judicial magistrate's court. The EC secretariat on February 3 sent a letter to Nitish, asking him to lodge the case.
   Others accused in the case are the Belkuchi Awami League candidate for upazila chairman Md Fazlul Haque Sarker, candidate for vice-chairman Gazi Abdul Hamid Akand, Bhangabari union parishad chairman Abdul Matin Pramanik and Md Hilton Rahman, assistant personal secretary to the minister.
   In accordance with the electoral rules, the accused may be fined or imprisoned for a term of two to seven years, or both, if they are found guilty of the offences, which are considered criminal offences.
   Another case was filed earlier against the Awami League lawmaker for the Cox's Bazar 4 constituency (Teknaf-Ukhia) , Abdur Rahman Bodi, for assaulting polling personnel during the upazila polls at Teknaf.
   The commission was forced to suspend polling in four upazilas, including Belkuchi and Taknaf, over intimidation, capturing of polling centres and snatching of ballot boxes.
   The first information report of the case claimed Soma Biswas, daughter of Latif Biswas, along with a number of thugs stormed into the Sohagpur Natunpara Government Primary School polling centre at about 9:00am, when balloting was going on, beat up the presiding officer M Masud Karim, headmaster of the Brahmangram Government Primary School , and snatched the ballot papers.
   According to the FIR, Latif Biswas along with his assistant private secretary, after casting his vote at the Alhaj Latifa Shahjahan Girls' High School centre, stormed into the Sohagpur Natunpara Government Primary School centre at about 10:30am when others accused had occupied the centre.
   Due to the presence of the minister, an anarchic situation was created, disrupting the voting process. At one stage, the assistant returning officer suspended polling at the centre. News of the minister's presence in the polling centre spread to all the other polling centres and spoilt the electoral environment.
   The FIR claimed the minister had violated Section 14 and 15 of the Upazila Parishad (Election Code of Conduct) Rule 2008 by entering the polling centre illegally and influencing the polling process. According to the rule, ministers, state ministers, deputy ministers and persons enjoying similar status cannot participate in electioneering.
   The Election Commission alleged a number of people, led by Fazlul Haque Sarker, Abdul Hamid Akand and Abdul Matin Pramanik, had physically assaulted and injured Mohammad Mosharrof Hossain, upazila election officer of Belkuchi, another officer Touhidul Islam and the upazila education officer at about 2:45pm in the hall of the upazila parishad.
   According to the FIR, the witnesses of the case are Sirajganj deputy commissioner Md Humayun Kabir, superintendent of police Md Alamgir Rahman, additional deputy commissioner Md Abdul Qaiyum, Belkuchi UNO Md Nasir Uddin, presiding officer Abul Hashem, assistant presiding officer Md Masud Karim and Bekuchi police officer-in-charge Md Arman Hossain.
   The upazila elections, held on January 22, were marked by stuffing of ballot boxes, expulsion of polling agents from polling centres and sporadic violence in which about 200 people were injured.
   The commission suspended elections to four, and postponed elections to two, upazila parishads.

 




__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] Tareq must be brought back in BNP ASAP

it is the grassroot leaders who want tareq back. if wrong headed hasina can lead bangladesh, the tareq is much better than

অতীতে বাংলাদেশের স্বার্থ বিসর্জন দিয়ে হলেও আলীগ ভারতের সাথে যেসব চুক্তি করেছে তার কোনটাই দাদারা বাস্তবায়ন করেনি । ভারতের সাথে আলীগের চুক্তি মানেই বাংলাদেশের স্বার্থ বিসর্জন নয় কি ?সর্বশক্তি দিয়ে প্রতিরোধ করা কি নাগরিক দায়িত্ব নয় ?


--- On Sun, 2/8/09, Salahuddin Ayubi <s_ayubi786@yahoo.com> wrote:
From: Salahuddin Ayubi <s_ayubi786@yahoo.com>
Subject: [Dahuk]: Re: [reform-bd] Tareq must be brought back in BNP ASAP
To: alochona@yahoogroups.com, chottala@yahoogroups.com, dahuk@yahoogroups.com, khabor@yahoogroups.com, notun_bangladesh@yahoogroups.com, sonarbangladesh@yahoogroups.com, "Amra Bangladesi" <amra-bangladesi@yahoogroups.com>, reform-bd@yahoogroups.com, tritiomatra@yahoogroups.com
Date: Sunday, February 8, 2009, 10:22 PM

Tariq is at the cause of present BNP debacle. It will serve BNP interset best if they keep this spoilt brat of Zia out of BNP and the party grows up a truly democratic party. Tariq just do not have the material in him  to lead this problematic country. Leadership has to come up from the grass root level.  Party must have a mechanism to produce leaders for the party. Just like it is done in Britain and other developed countries.
                         Ayubi

--- On Mon, 2/9/09, mahathir of bd <wouldbemahathirofbd @yahoo.com> wrote:
From: mahathir of bd <wouldbemahathirofbd @yahoo.com>
Subject: [reform-bd] Tareq must be brought back in BNP ASAP
To: alochona@yahoogroup s.com, chottala@yahoogroup s.com, dahuk@yahoogroups. com, khabor@yahoogroups. com, notun_bangladesh@ yahoogroups. com, sonarbangladesh@ yahoogroups. com, "Amra Bangladesi" <amra-bangladesi@ yahoogroups. com>, reform-bd@yahoogrou ps.com, tritiomatra@ yahoogroups. com
Date: Monday, February 9, 2009, 12:00 AM

মতবিনিময়ে যেসব দাবি বিএনপি'র তৃণমূল নেতাদের
কাফি কামাল: বর্তমান রাজনৈতিক পরিস্থিতিতে জামায়াতের সঙ্গে বিএনপি জোটবদ্ধ থাকলে দলের লাভের চেয়ে ক্ষতিই বেশি হবে। এখন রাজনৈতিক দুর্বলতাকে অস্বীকার করলে ভবিষ্যতে মুখোমুখি হতে হবে আরও কঠিন বিপর্যয়ের। এবার কোন পকেট কমিটি মেনে নেয়া হবে না। বিতর্কিত দুর্নীতিবাজদের বাদ দিয়ে কাউন্সিলের মাধ্যমে নির্বাচিত কমিটি গঠন করে সংগঠনকে গতিশীল করতে হবে। দলের সিনিয়র যুগ্ম মহাসচিব তারেক রহমান দলকে সাংগঠনিকভাবে গোছাতে যে উদ্যোগ নিয়েছিলেন তা অব্যাহত রাখতে হবে। তাকে আবারও দলের মূল নেতৃত্বে নিয়ে আনতে হবে। এ নির্বাচন কমিশনের অধীনে নির্বাচনে যাওয়া উচিত হয়নি। একটি সম্মানজনক সমাধানের মাধ্যমে বিএনপি'র সংসদে যাওয়া ও ইতিবাচক ভূমিকা রাখা উচিত। সংসদে যাওয়ার বিকল্প নেই। বিএনপি'র সাংগঠনিক পুনর্গঠনকে কেন্দ্র করে ৩রা ফেব্রুয়ারি থেকে দেশের বিভিন্ন জেলা থেকে দলের কেন্দ্রীয় কার্যালয়ে সাক্ষাৎকার ও মতবিনিময় সভায় যোগ দেয়া তৃণমূল নেতারা প্রতিদিনই কেন্দ্রীয় নেতাদের এসব দাবি জানাচ্ছেন। গতকাল বিভিন্ন বিভাগীয় সাংগঠনিক দায়িত্বপ্রাপ্ত কেন্দ্রীয় নেতা ও তৃণমূল নেতাদের সঙ্গে কথা বলে এ তথ্য জানা গেছে। গত ৩রা ফেব্রুয়ারি থেকে শুরু হওয়া সাংগঠনিক পুনর্গঠন প্রক্রিয়ায় গতকাল পর্যন্ত ১৪টি জেলার প্রায় দু'শতাধিক উপজেলা ও পৌর কমিটির তৃণমূল নেতারা সাক্ষাৎকার ও মতবিনিময় সভায় অংশ নিয়ে তাদের বক্তব্য তুলে ধরেছেন। প্রথম দিন মাগুরা, দ্বিতীয় দিন হবিগঞ্জ ও তৃতীয় দিন পটুয়াখালী, ব্রাহ্মণবাড়িয়া ও জামালপুর, চতুর্থ দিন সুনামগঞ্জ ও নড়াইল, পঞ্চম দিন নওগাঁ, ঝালকাঠি ও লক্ষ্মীপুর এবং গতকাল মেহেরপুর ও চুয়াডাঙ্গা এবং ফেনী জেলার নেতারা মতবিনিময় সভায় অংশ নেন। ছয়টি বিভাগীয় সাংগঠনিক টিমের নেতৃত্বে এ প্রক্রিয়া চলবে ২৮শে ফেব্রুয়ারি পর্যন্ত। তৃণমূল নেতারা বলেন, নির্বাচন ও সাংগঠনিক জোটবদ্ধতার বিষয়টিকে আলাদা বিবেচনা করে জামায়াতের ওপর নির্ভরশীলতা কমাতে হবে। নবম জাতীয় নির্বাচনে জামায়াত নির্ভরশীলতার কারণে ফল বিপর্যয় হয়েছে। অনেক এলাকায় বিএনপির মধ্যে অন্তর্কোন্দল সৃষ্টি করেছে জামায়াত। তৃণমূল নেতাদের মতে, একটি সম্মানজনক সমাধানের মাধ্যমে বিএনপি'র সংসদে যাওয়া ও ইতিবাচক ভূমিকা রাখা উচিত। সংসদে যাওয়ার বিকল্প নেই। তারা বলেন, এবার কোন পকেট কমিটি চাই না। পকেট কমিটি করা হলে তা মেনে নেয়া হবে না। বিতর্কিত ও দুর্নীতিবাজদের বাদ দিয়ে কাউন্সিলের মাধ্যমে নির্বাচিত কমিটি গঠন করে সংগঠনকে গতিশীল করতে হবে। ২৯শে ডিসেম্বরের জাতীয় নির্বাচনে ফল বিপর্যয়ের কারণ বিশ্লেষণ করে তারা বলেন, রাজনৈতিক দল দায়িত্বপালনে ব্যর্থ হওয়ায় ও রাজনৈতিক সিদ্ধান্তের নানা ত্রুটির ফাঁক-ফোকরে বিস্তার লাভ করেছে দেশী-বিদেশী ষড়যন্ত্র। রাজনৈতিক নেতাদের বিতর্কিত করার মাধ্যমে প্রভাবিত করা হয়েছে নির্বাচনকে। বরগুনা পৌর বিএনপি'র সাংগঠনিক সম্পাদক শফিকুল আলম টিপু বলেন, দেশী-বিদেশী ষড়যন্ত্রের অংশ হিসেবে প্রশাসনের পক্ষপাতিত্বের পাশাপাশি শীর্ষ নেতাদের ভুল সিদ্ধান্ত, বেইমানি, দলের একটি অংশের ষড়যন্ত্র, সংস্কারপন্থি প্রার্থী ও স্থানীয় নেতাকর্মীদের দূরত্বের কারণে এ বিপর্যয় হয়েছে। এছাড়া দলের কিছু সিনিয়র নেতা নির্বাচন বাণিজ্য করেছেন। সংস্কারপন্থি প্রার্থীদের প্রতিনিধি হিসেবে মেনে নিতে পারেনি তৃণমূল নেতাকর্মীরা। চুয়াডাঙ্গার আলমডাঙ্গা উপজেলা বিএনপি সম্পাদক মজিবুর রহমান বলেন, বেশির ভাগ প্রার্থীর সঙ্গে স্থানীয় কর্মী-সমর্থকদের যোগাযোগ বিচ্ছিন্নতা, প্রার্থী নির্বাচনে ভুল ও জোটের শরিক জামায়াতের নিষ্ক্রিয়তার কারণে নির্বাচনী প্রচার ছিল সীমাবদ্ধ। গত দুই বছরে নানা নির্যাতনের কারণে ভয়ে কর্মীরা সক্রিয় হতে পারেনি। দলের নির্বাচনী বিপর্যয়ে সাংগঠনিক ক্ষতির চেয়ে সামাজিক ক্ষতি হয়েছে অনেক বেশি। তৃণমূল নেতাদের মতে, এ নির্বাচন কমিশনের অধীনে নির্বাচনে যাওয়া উচিত হয়নি। উপজেলা নির্বাচনে কেন্দ্রীয় কমিটির ত্বরিত সিদ্ধান্ত ও জোরালো ভূমিকার প্রয়োজন ছিল। চুয়াডাঙ্গা সদর থানা বিএনপি সম্পাদক রেজাউল করিম মুকুট বলেন, দুই বছরে বিভিন্ন কারণে বিএনপি কয়েক ভাগে ভাগ হয়ে পড়ায় নির্বাচনে বিপর্যয় ঘটেছে। বিভক্ত দল নিয়ে যুদ্ধে জয়ী হওয়া যায় না। তৃণমূল নেতাদের মতে, দু'বছর পরপর কমিটি গঠনের কথা থাকলেও অনেক এলাকায় কমিটি গঠন হয়েছে ছয় থেকে আট বছর আগে। মেহেরপুর জেলা বিএনপির ভারপ্রাপ্ত সম্পাদক ইলিয়াস হোসেন বলেন, বিতর্কিত নেতাদের দলের ফ্রন্টলাইন থেকে আপাতত দূরে রেখে স্বচ্ছ ও ত্যাগী নেতৃত্বকে সামনে আনতে হবে। কমিটিতে ঘটাতে হবে নবীন ও প্রবীণের ভারসাম্যপূর্ণ সমন্বয়। সাংগঠনিক পরিধি বাড়াতে সংগঠনকে গণমুখী করে তুলতে হবে। ফেনীর কয়েকটি উপজেলা বিএনপি'র সিনিয়র নেতাদের দাবি, জেলায় দলের ভাইস চেয়ারম্যান মেজর (অব) সাঈদ এস্কান্দারের হস্তক্ষেপ বন্ধ করতে হবে। বরগুনা পৌর বিএনপি সম্পাদক আনোয়ার হোসেন বলেন, দলের সাবেক মন্ত্রী-এমপিদের বিরুদ্ধে দুর্নীতির অভিযোগ একেবারে মিথ্যা নয়। অনেক মন্ত্রী-এমপি নির্বাচনে ক্ষমতার যথেচ্ছ ব্যবহার করেছেন। তবে সত্যতার চেয়ে প্রচার হয়েছে অনেক বেশি। কোন কোন ক্ষেত্রে লঘু অপরাধে বিশেষ আদালতে গুরুতর শাস্তি দেয়া হয়েছে। চুয়াডাঙ্গার আলমডাঙ্গা পৌর বিএনপি সভাপতি খন্দকার হামিদুল ইসলাম আজম বলেন, তারেক রহমান দলকে সাংগঠনিকভাবে গোছাতে যে উদ্যোগ নিয়েছিলেন তা অব্যাহত রাখতে হবে। বাড়াতে হবে দলের কেন্দ্রীয় নেতাদের সাংগঠনিক সফর ও সম্মেলন কর্মসূচি। তারেক রহমানের সাংগঠনিক দক্ষতার কারণে তাকে টার্গেট করেই বিতর্কিত করা হয়েছে। তাকে আবারও দলের মূল নেতৃত্বে নিয়ে আসতে হবে। গত নির্বাচনে তৃণমূল নেতাদের মধ্যে তীব্রভাবে তার অভাব অনুভূত হয়েছে। তিনি যে সাংগঠনিকভাবে দলকে গোছাতে শুরু করেছিলেন সেভাবে হলে এতবড় ভরাডুবি হতো না। এদিকে গতকাল মতবিনিময় সভা চলাকালে তৃণমূল নেতারা একে অন্যের সামনে স্বাভাবিকভাবে কথা বলতে অস্বস্তিবোধ করছিলেন। বরগুনা সদর বিএনপি'র সাংগঠনিক সম্পাদক আবদুল হক হাওলাদার বলেন, অতীতের ধারাবাহিকতায় চাপিয়ে দেয়া কমিটি মেনে নেবে না তৃণমূল নেতাকর্মীরা। ১১ই জানুয়ারির পর থেকে বিভিন্ন নির্যাতন নিপীড়নের ফলে তারা প্রতিপক্ষ রাজনৈতিক দলের পাশাপাশি দলীয় কেন্দ্রীয় নেতাদের ওপরও ক্ষুব্ধ। ফেনীর দাগনভূঞা উপজেলা বিএনপি'র সভাপতি দেলোয়ার হোসেন ও সাধারণ সম্পাদক আবদুল মতিন চৌধুরী বলেন, বর্তমান পরিস্থিতিকে সূুক্ষ্মভাবে বিচার বিশ্লেষণ করে দলের তৃণমূল থেকে কেন্দ্র পর্যায়ের নেতৃত্ব ঢেলে সাজাতে হবে। জেলা পর্যায়ে অনেক ত্যাগী ও প্রজ্ঞাবান নেতা আছেন যারা দলের কেন্দ্রীয় নেতৃত্বে আসার যোগ্যতা রাখেন। এবার দলের চেয়ারপারসনকে নেতৃত্ব নির্বাচনে কঠিন মানসিকতার পরিচয় দিয়ে তাদের সামনে নিয়ে আসতে হবে। ভাঙতে হবে বিভিন্ন জেলা কেন্দ্রীয় কোটারি চক্র।
 


অতীতে বাংলাদেশের স্বার্থ বিসর্জন দিয়ে হলেও আলীগ ভারতের সাথে যেসব চুক্তি করেছে তার কোনটাই দাদারা বাস্তবায়ন করেনি । ভারতের সাথে আলীগের চুক্তি মানেই বাংলাদেশের স্বার্থ বিসর্জন নয় কি ?সর্বশক্তি দিয়ে প্রতিরোধ করা কি নাগরিক দায়িত্ব নয় ?





__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] February 21st, 2009: Invitation To Join First Online Conference for International Bangladeshi Professional Association [IPABDP]

Dear All,

        You are cordially invited to join first online conference for Bangladeshi Professionals, sponsored by e2D Consulting services, MN, USA.

 

        To complete the registration processes please fill out the registration form attached with this mail. If you have friends who would like to join this conference please forward this mail to them.

 

        We are pleased to announce that Mr. Kamal Quadir founder & CEO of CellBazaar will be giving opening keynote for this conference.

 

        Participants needs to have internet access and capability to dial a USA conference telephone bridge to participate in this conference. Last date of registration is February 17th, 2009.

 

You can find more about this conference and actively participate on the organization process by following the below two web user group links:

Linked in: http://www.linkedin.com/groups?gid=1780723

Face-Book: http://www.facebook.com/home.php?#/group.php?gid=47996073902

 

     Below is the session details of the conference:

 

IPABDA Conference Schedule

Sessions

Participating?

Dhaka

Washington, DC

UTC-time/GMT

Opening Key Note: Mr. Kamal Quadir

Yes/No

Sat 10:00 PM

Sat 11:00 AM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 16:00:00

Invest Bangladesh

Yes/No

Sat 11:00 PM

Sat 12:00 Noon

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 17:00:00

Break

 

Midnight Sat-Sun

Sat 1:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 18:00:00

Work Overseas

Yes/No

Sun 1:00 AM

Sat 2:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 19:00:00

Invest Overseas

Yes/No

Sun 2:00 AM

Sat 3:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 20:00:00

Social Activism

Yes/No

Sun 3:00 AM

Sat 4:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 21:00:00

Work Bangladesh

Yes/No

Sun 4:00 AM

Sat 5:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 22:00:00

Closing Key Note

Yes/No

Sun 5:00 AM

Sat 6:00 PM

Saturday, February 21, 2009 at 23:00:00

 

 

If you need to convert this time to your local time please use the below meeting planner:

http://www.timeanddate.com/worldclock/meeting.html

 

Looking forward to seeing you all over online, please send the registration completion by February 17th. We can only have 20 participants per session, so seating is very limited. If we do not receive the completed registration by due time, we cannot guarantee your participation.

 

Best regards,

Conference organizers

IPABDP

mail @ icsql.com

 

 

 



__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] Racism and Religious Desecration as US Policy:Islamophobia, a Retrospective

Racism and Religious Desecration as US Policy:Islamophobia, a Retrospective

 
By TRISH SCHUH
It was the potshot heard round the world that touched off a counter-crusade. Packaged in western free speech cliches, and marketed as innocent satire, the newspaper Jylland-Posten's depiction of the Prophet Muhammad as a terrorist/suicide bomber with a ticking bomb for a turban was "provocation-entrapment" propaganda. Dual-use entertainment, in this case frivolous caricature, is an unexamined aspect of "full spectrum information dominance." The US Secretary of Defense Donald Rumsfeld's "Information Operations Roadmap" mandates that 'information warfare' utilize all cultural venues to further its agenda- news, posters, books, movies, art, internet, and music etc.
 
Can comedy be far behind? At recent CIA training sessions in Dubai, Iranian opposition agent provocateurs were taught the importance of mockery and ridicule when used to discredit and 'demythologize' an enemy or incite against it. Even populist actions like grafitti "could embolden the student movement and provoke a general government crackdown, which could then be used as a pretext to 'spark' a mass uprising that appeared to be spontaneous." (Asia Times, Mar 14, 06). Such provocation tactics operated in the cartoon intifada, as well as in US Embassy-coordinated "color revolutions".

As a free speech crusader, Flemming Rose, Jyllands-Posten's editor behind the Muhammad cartoons (and ally/author of a Daniel Pipes profile "The Threat from Islam"), had earlier refused to publish denigrating cartoons of Jesus, fearing it would "offend readers." Jylland-Posten also rescinded sponsorship of a Holocaust cartoon contest for the same reason. Kurt Westergaard, Jylland-Posten's 'Muhammad bomb' illustrator even transcribed a Koranic verse onto Muhammad's turban to reinforce his message. Westergaard later admitted to The Herald of Glasgow, Scotland that "terrorism" which he said got "spiritual ammunition" from Islam was the inspiration for that message.
If propaganda is a weapon of war, Islam is under carpet bombing. Nazi propagandist Joseph Goebbels described the methods, which define those used today: "Concentrating the fire of all the media on one particular point- a single theme, a single enemy, a single idea- the campaign uses this concentration of all media, but progressively..."
 
Theme: "War on Terror" Enemy: Muslims. Addressing the 2006 AIPAC "Now is the Time to Stop Iran" Conference, Israeli Ambassador to the UN, Daniel Gillerman summarized the Idea: "While it may be true- and probably is- that not all Muslims are terrorists, it also happens to be true that nearly all terrorists are Muslim." Former Iranian President Mohammad Khatami put it another way: "the West needs an enemy, and this time it is Islam. And Islamophobia becomes part of all policies of the great powers, of hegemonic powers."

Is Islamophobia de facto state policy? Italian prime minister Silvio Berlusconi declared in 2001 that Western civilization is superior to the Islamic World: "We should be confident of the superiority of our civilization, which consists of a value system that has given people widespread prosperity in those countries that embrace it, and guarantees respect for human rights." He added that this superiority entitled the West to "occidentalize and conquer new people." Another Italian official MP Roberto Calderoni flaunted his Muhammad cartoon T-shirt on TV, warning of a an "Islamic attack on the West." French Interior Minister Nicolas Sarkozy pronounced Muslim immigrants "gangrene" and "scum," and one Danish MP labeled Muslims "a cancer in Denmark."
 
In America, Illinois Congressman Mark Kirk commented: "I'm okay with discrimination against young Arab males from terrorist-producing states." Texas Congressman Sam Johnson bragged to a crowd of veterans that he had advised Bush to nuke Syria, and Colorado Congressman Tom Tancredo advocated wiping out Mecca to get even with Muslims for terrorist attacks. Recently the Bush administration itself revealed its plans to "nuke Iran" with bunker buster bombs.

Zionist Daniel Pipes, a representative at the Congress-sponsored think tank US Institute for Peace, (who was appointed by Bush despite heavy public protest against Pipe's racism) recently diagnosed Muslims as carriers of a sinister, latent psychopathic contagion: "Individuals may appear law-abiding and reasonable, but they are part of a totalitarian movement, and as such, all must be considered potential killers... This is what I have dubbed the Sudden Jihad Syndrome, whereby normal-appearing Muslims abruptly become violent. It has the awful but legitimate consequence of casting suspicion on all Muslims. Who knows whence the next jihadi? How can one be confident a law-abiding Muslim will not suddenly erupt in a homocidal rage?"
 
Muslims' angry reactions to the cartoon provocation unwittingly served a goal of Pipe's Anti-Islamist Institute: "the delegitimation of the Islamists. We seek to have them shunned by the government, the media, the churches, the academy and the corporate world." For once, Israel, America and Europe were united to protect civilization's free speech virtues against "crazed, rampaging", "dirty arabs" or, as Pipes himself once remarked, "brown-skinned peoples cooking strange foods and not exactly maintaining Germanic standards of hygiene."
 
I asked Pipes about the systemic racism and Muslim/Arab 'terrorist' stereotypes in the US media. Pipes said: "I would strongly, strongly disagree. There is an enormous amount of media that is very, very positive about Muslims, an enormous amount. I see it everyday. There is a steady stream of media that is very positive about Muslims- steady, steady, steady. I see it everyday- all the time..." When persistently pressed to name five positive stories or Muslim role models among this plethora of good news- authors, academics, lawyers, celebrities etc. Pipes could not give a single example. But he easily supplied numerous names of prominent Arab Americans allegedly 'linked' to terrorism.
 
Despite disclaimers, bigoted, hideous and contemptuous anti-Muslim content continues unabated: hooded corpses in Abu Ghraib displayed by jovial "thumbs up" troops, force-fed hunger strikers at Guantanamo (who Donald Rumsfeld wisecracked were "on a diet"), refugee camps flattened, Palestinians starving, taunts of "Taliban lady boys" after US troops had set fire to Afghan bodies, ubiquitous car bombings, wedding parties crushed, mosques massacred, civilians attacked with cluster bombs and daisy cutters. Depleted uranium mutating future generations, and a thousand Iraqi pilgrims stampeded to death in an hour... In the midst of which President Bush pantomimed & joked about missing WMD's to an applauding, jeering Radio & Television Correspondents Association that call themselves a press corp. Antics befitting a noncombatant President who greeted the initial bombing of Iraq with pumped fists: "I feel good!" (BBC) "See in my line of work you got to keep repeating things over and over and over again for the truth to sink in, to kind of catapult the propaganda." (George W Bush, 5/24/05)
 
This state-sponsored smirking has trickled down to spawn a climate of recreational cruelty in the US military. Reflecting anti-Muslim propaganda while perpetuating it, is the "Rumsfeld Contingent" of the armed forces. Deputy Undersecretary of Defense, Lt. Gen. William Jerry Boykin propagated hate at the grassroots level in dozens of speeches to church groups, saying that the war on terror was actually spiritual warfare, with the enemy 'Satan' being embodied by Islam. Speaking of God versus Allah he said: "Well, you know what I knew, that my God was bigger than his. I knew that my God was a real God, and his was an idol." Secretary of Defense Rumsfeld defended Boykin, so it was unsurprising that after Abu Ghraib crimes erupted Boykin found "no pattern of misconduct."
 
Dropping down the chain of command, Marine Corp Lt. Gen. James Mattis's comments were caught by AP. "Actually, it's a lot of fun to fight. You know it's a hell of a hoot. It's fun to shoot some people. I'll be right upfront with you, I like brawling." Drawing on the 'Muslim misogynist' stereotype, Mattis added that Muslim men were wife-beaters and continued: "You know, guys like that ain't got no manhood left anyway. So it's a hell of alot of fun to shoot them." Some troops on the ground echoed this "raghead" ethos as they shot Iraqis.
 
Or shot down their sacred symbols. In May, 2005, worldwide Muslim reaction compelled Newsweek to retract a story about US interrogators flushing the Koran down a toilet at Guantanamo Bay. Secretary of Defense Rumsfeld maintained that the revelation was not true, and demanded that Newsweek explain to the Muslim world "the care that the US military takes" to respect Islamic beliefs.
 
But such behavior had been documented independently elsewhere. The Denver Post: prisoners were "forced to watch copies of the Koran being flushed down toilets" (January, 2005), Financial Times: "they were beaten and had their Korans thrown into toilets" (Oct 28, 2004), NY Daily News: "They would kick the Koran, throw it into the toilet and generally disrespect it." (Aug. 5, 2004), The Independent UK: "Guards allegedly threw prisoners' Korans into toilets" (Aug 5, 2004), The Observer UK: "copies of the Koran would be trampled on by soldiers and, on one occasion, thrown into a toilet bucket." (March 14, 2004), Washington Post: "American soldiers insulted Islam by sitting on the Koran or dumping their sacred text into a toilet to taunt them" (March 26, 2003). These were but a few of similar media reports over a period of years.
 
Other instances of Islamic desecration were also recorded. One online fundraiser sold printed toilet paper with the words "Koran, the Holy Quran" which was then distributed to mosques and the media with a letter claiming the Koran was a "cookbook for terrorists" and incited violence. The Mercury News revealed that flyers posted on a Sacramento National Guard military base extolled World War 1 General John Pershing as a hero for executing "Muslim terrorists" with bullets dipped in pigs blood, thus excluding them from Paradise. WorldNetDaily reported on a US Army Reserve recruit's contest that used pages from the Koran to make porcine figures. His website pabaah.com showed a paper mache' pig with a US flag on its back, and included paper mache instructions and links to get free Korans.
 
Some troop contests were flippant in a physical way. At Camp Nama adjacent to Baghdad Airport, The New York Times reported that detainees were bruised after being used for target practice by soldiers playing in the High Five Paintball Club. Human Rights Watch later assessed that prisoners were sometimes tortured as a form of stress relief for soldiers to help while away the hours. "Some days we would just get bored so we would have everyone sit in a corner and then make them get in a pyramid. We did that for amusement." One soldier added "...it was like a game ...for sport.." This R & R earned the 82nd Airborne at FOB Mercury a prized nickname from terrified Iraqis: "Murderous Maniacs". Departing military personnel who did a 'good job' were later awarded by commanders with trophies- a detainee's black hood, and a piece of tile from the medical office that had once held Saddam Hussein. (After the 1990 Iraq War, one soldier tried to smuggle an Iraqi's limb home in his duffel bag as a trophy under the first Bush/Cheney administration.)
 
At Abu Ghraib, Sgt Michael J. Smith laughed and partied with rival dog handlers as they competed to see who could outscare and humiliate Iraqi prisoners (dogs are considered unclean and human contact is forbidden by Islam) by siccing ferocious, violent killer dogs on them. Smith said: "My buddy and I are having a contest to see if we can get them to defecate on themselves because we've already had some urinate on themselves." Then in a show of good canine conscience (or just good sportsmanship), one trainer's Belgian shepherd turned its back on the detainee and instead attacked the interrogator.
 
Michael Blake, an Iraq veteran explained that the military indoctinated troops with the idea "Islam is Evil" and "they hate us." This attitude facilitated the abuse and killing of civilians, and was not just 'a few bad apples'. (There are around 2000 unreleased torture images). "Most of the guys I was with believed it", he added. Maj. Gen. Charles Swannack, a former 82nd Airborne commander insisted that responsibility for such abuses ultimately lead "directly back to Secretary Rumsfeld," as an architect of the torture policy.

Lower level troops prosecuted to deflect responsibility from Rumsfeld have also testified that they were following orders from above. An official report in 2005 by the Army Inspector General confirms that authorities at the highest level sanctioned the crimes. The report documented Rumsfeld's direct, personal briefings by Army Major interrogator Geoffrey Miller.

British Brigadier Alan Sharp (American Bronze Star winner for writing the "coalition campaign plan") disapproved of the gung ho, swaggering "streak of Hollywood" displayed by US troops. Acknowledging that such "heroics" made for good television back in the States, he warned that heavily armed Americans boasting "how many Iraqis have been killed by US forces today" was no 'hearts and minds' winning tool.

But the example had been set after 911 by the "gunslingin', nuke-totin'" swagger of Cowboy-in-Chief Dubya Bush. His blustering wisecrack "Osama- Wanted: Dead or Alive" mimicked posters of old Hollywood westerns. The New York Times reported that major Tinsel Town executives were working with top Bush advisor Karl Rove to revive the former propaganda partnership between the entertainment industry and the Department of Defense. "Hollywood Now Plays Cowboys and Arabs", ran one headline. (Ironically, Bush's grandfather Prescott claimed to have stolen the skull of legendary American Indian warrior Geronimo for his college secret society. It was proudly kept on display as a trophy).

In 2004, the Pentagon previewed its own "coming attractions." Marines staged a desert "gladiators' Ben Hur" drill in full historic costume- togas, trojan helmuts, and shields while swinging spiked truncheons to "psych up for a planned invasion" against Fallujah. "Friends, Romans, countryman, fend off their spears. When in Fallujah, do as the Romans do" the New York Post quipped. White phosphorus 'burning at the stake' was strictly offscreen. As Lt. Col. Gary Brandl said in the film Fallujah: "The enemy has got a face. He's called Satan. He's in Fallujah. And we're going to destroy him."
Internet audiences could catch candids of Iraqi dead "just for fun". At undermars.com, troops posted photos of bloody faces ground to a pulp. Others showed a birthday candle stuffed into a smashed skull, and various decapitated heads. Evoking Bush's cowboy spirit, one caption read: "i'm an indian outlaw... look my first scalp."

NowThatsFuckedUp.com accepted photos of Iraqi war crimes and atrocities as currency to buy pornography when credit card companies refused to ok payment in dollars.
After a brief outcry from Iraqi expatriates, the site was closed and diverted to an address called barbecuestoppers.com. There troops laughed and gloated over 'baked', charred and hideously disfigured Iraqi cadavers, with captions like "Die, Haji die." One picture showed a 'barbecued' corpse steeped in its own blood and entrails labeled "what every Iraqi should look like." The US Department of Defense is aware of the site, but it is still accessible to voyeurs despite being in violation of Geneva Conventions.

Unfortunately, this avalanche of damaging associations have increased Americans' prejudice against Islam. A March 2006 ABC News poll found 46 percent view Islam negatively, up from 39 percent in the months after September 11, 2001. Americans who believe that Islam promotes violence has risen from 14 percent in 2002 to 33 percent today. Former US president Bill Clinton warned: "So now what are we going to do? Replace anti-Semitic prejudice with anti-Islamic prejudice?"

It seems so. In 2005, for the first time since the atomic devastation of Japan, an Associated Press poll found that half of all Americans would approve the use of atomic bombs, especially against terrorist targets. A mushroom cloud of anti-Muslim hate, with a sickly "humorous" spin, has been winning American 'hearts and minds' into acceptance of the Bush administration's nuclear attack against the "axis of evil" terror sponsor- Islamic Republic of Iran.

Meanwhile, another cheap shot has recently been fired at Islam. A provocative 'Muhammad cartoon' depicts the Prophet Muhammad cut in half, and burning in Hell, next to a woman among burning coals. Its editor says the cartoon represents policy towards Islam and that any angry reaction to it could serve to further alienate Muslims: "if the cartoon provoked an attack, it would only 'confirm the idiotic positions' of Muslim extremists." Don't forget to laugh.

Trish Schuh was a co-founder of Military Families Support Network and is a member of Military Reporters & Editors covering the middle east.



__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___

[ALOCHONA] Excellent - CRISIS IN THE HEARTLAND by PETER GOWAN

 one of most comprehensive & incisive analysis of the financial crisis I have read so far. A must read!

CRISIS IN THE HEARTLAND

Consequences of the New Wall Street System

PETER GOWAN

New Left Review

http://www.newleftreview.org/?page=article&view=2759

 

Peter Gowan is Professor of International Relations at London Metropolitan University and course director of the MA in International Relations.

 

The long credit crunch that began in the Atlantic world in August 2007 is strange in its extraordinary scope and intensity. Mainstream discourse, referring to a 'sub-prime' crisis, implies that the credit crunch has been caused, rather than triggered, by a bubble in the real economy. This is at best naïve: after all, the bursting of an equally large bubble in the Spanish housing market led to no such blow-out in the domestic banking system. [1] The notion that falling house prices could shut down half of all lending in the us economy within a matter of months—and not just mortgages, but car loans, credit-card receivables, commercial paper, commercial property and corporate debt—makes no sense. In quantitative terms this amounted to a credit shrinkage of about $24 trillion dollars, nearly double usgdp. [2] Erstwhile lenders were soon running not just from sub-prime securities but from the supposedly safest debt of all, the 'super senior' category, whose price by the end of 2007 was a tenth of what it had been just a year before. [3]

 

An understanding of the credit crunch requires us to transcend the commonsense idea that changes in the so-called real economy drive outcomes in a supposed financial superstructure. Making this 'epistemological break' is not easy. One reason why so few economists saw a crisis coming, or failed to grasp its scale even after it had hit, was that their models had assumed both that financial systems 'work', in the sense of efficiently aiding the operations of the real economy, and that financial trends themselves are of secondary significance. [4] Thus the assumption that the massive bubble in oil prices between the autumn of 2007 and the summer of 2008 was caused by supply-and-demand factors, rather than by financial operators who, reeling from the onset of the crisis, blew the price from $70 a barrel to over $140 in less than a year, before letting the bubble burst last June; a cycle with hugely negative 'real economy' effects. Similar explanations were tendered for soaring commodity prices over the same period; yet these were largely caused by institutional investors, money-market and pension funds, fleeing from lending to the Wall Street banks, who poured hundreds of billions of dollars into commodities indices, while hedge funds with their backs against the wall pumped up bubbles in coffee and cocoa. [5]

 

Breaking with the orthodoxy that it was 'real economy' actors that caused the crisis carries a political price: it means that blame can no longer be pinned on mortgage borrowers for the credit crunch, on the Chinese for the commodities bubble, or on restrictive Arab producers for the sudden soaring of oil. Yet it may allow us to understand otherwise inexplicable features of the crisis; not least, as we shall see, the extraordinary growth of sub-prime itself. We will thus take as our starting point the need to explore the structural transformation of the American financial system over the past twenty-five years. I will argue that a New Wall Street System has emerged in the us during this period, producing new actors, new practices and new dynamics. The resulting financial structure-cum-agents has been the driving force behind the present crisis. En route, it proved spectacularly successful for the richest groups in the us: the financial sector constituted by far the most profitable component of the American and British economies and their most important 'export' earner. In 2006, no less than 40 per cent of American corporate profits accrued to the financial sector. [6] But the new structure necessarily produced the dynamics that led towards blow-out.

 

This analysis is not offered as a mono-causal explanation of the crisis. A fundamental condition, creating the soil in which the New Wall Street System could grow and flourish, was the project of the 'fiat' dollar system, the privatization of exchange-rate risk and the sweeping away of exchange controls—all euphemized as 'financial globalization'. Furthermore, the system could not have risen and flourished if it had not offered answers—however ultimately pathological—to a range of deep-seated problems within American capitalism overall. There is thus a rational, dialectical kernel in the superficial distinction between financial superstructure and the 'real' us economy. In what follows, I will first sketch the main elements of the New Wall Street System, and briefly show how its crisis took such spectacular forms. I will then argue that, to understand the deeper roots of the malaise, we do indeed need to probe into the overall socio-economic and socio-political characteristics of American capitalism as it has evolved over the past twenty-five years. I will raise the possibility of systemic alternatives, including that of a public-utility credit and banking model. Finally, I will consider the international dynamics unleashed by the present crisis and their implications for what I have elsewhere described as the Dollar–Wall Street Regime. [7]

 

i. the new wall street system

The structure and dynamics of Wall Street banking changed dramatically in the quarter of a century after the mid-1980s. The main features of the new system include: (i) the rise of the lender-trader model; (ii) speculative arbitrage and asset-price bubble-blowing; (iii) the drive for maximizing leverage and balance-sheet expansion; (iv) the rise of the shadow banking system, with its London arm, and associated 'financial innovations'; (v) the salience of the money markets and their transformation into funders of speculative trading in asset bubbles; (vi) the new centrality of credit derivatives. These changes mutually re-enforced each other, forming an integrated and complex whole, which then disintegrated in the course of 2008. We will briefly examine each of them in turn.

 

Trading models

For most of the post-war period, Wall Street investment banks engaged in very little securities trading on their own account, as opposed to trading on behalf of clients; while the big depository commercial banks shunned such activity. But from the mid-1980s on, proprietary trading in financial and other assets became an increasingly central activity for the investment banks, and for many commercial banks, too. This turn was connected, firstly, to the new volatility in foreign-exchange markets after the dismantling of Bretton Woods; and then to the opportunities created by domestic financial liberalization, above all the scrapping of capital controls and the opening of other national financial systems to American operators. These changes offered opportunities for a massive expansion of Wall Street trading activity, which would become a crucial source of profits for the investment banks. [8] The turn towards speculative proprietary trading was pioneered by Salomon Brothers, whose Arbitrage Group was established in 1977 and acquired extraordinary profitability under John Meriwether during the 1980s. [9]

 

As well as trading on their own account, the Wall Street banks became increasingly involved in lending funds for other bodies to use in their trading activities: hedge funds, so-called private equity groups (trading in companies), or special investment vehicles (sivs) and conduits, created by the investment banks themselves. [10] Such lending, known in the jargon as prime brokerage, was also an extremely profitable activity for the Wall Street banks: for many, their single greatest earner. [11] This turn to the lender-trader model did not mean that the investment banks ceased their traditional activities in investment banking, broking, fund management, etc. But these activities acquired a new significance in that they provided the banks with vast amounts of real-time market information of great value for their trading activity. [12]

 

Trading activity here does not mean long-term investment, Warren Buffett-style, in this or that security, but buying and selling financial and real assets to exploit—not least by generating—price differences and price shifts. This type of 'speculative arbitrage' became a central focus, not only for the investment banks but for commercial banks as well. [13] So, too, did the related effort to generate asset-price bubbles. Time and time again, Wall Street could enter a particular market, generate a price bubble within it, make big speculative profits, then withdraw, bursting the bubble. Such activity was very easy in so-called emerging market economies with small stock or bond markets. The Wall Street banks gained a wealth of experience in blowing such bubbles in the Polish, Czech or Russian stock markets in the 1990s and then bursting them to great profit. The dot.com bubble in the us then showed how the same operation could be carried through in the heartland without any significant loss to the Wall Street banks (as opposed to some European operators, notably insurance companies, eager to profit from the bubble but hit by the burst).

 

Both the Washington regulators and Wall Street evidently believed that together they could manage bursts. [14] This meant there was no need to prevent such bubbles from occurring: on the contrary it is patently obvious that both regulators and operators actively generated them, no doubt believing that one of the ways of managing bursts was to blow another dynamic bubble in another sector: after dot.com, the housing bubble; after that, an energy-price or emerging-market bubble, etc. This may seem to imply a formidably centralized financial power operating at the heart of these markets. Indeed: the New Wall Street System was dominated by just five investment banks, holding over $4 trillion of assets, and able to call upon or move literally trillions more dollars from the institutions behind them, such as the commercial banks, the money-market funds, pension funds, and so on. The system was a far cry from the decentralized market with thousands of players, all slavish price-takers, depicted by neo-classical economics. Indeed, the operational belief systems of what might be called the Greenspan-Rubin-Paulson milieu seems to have been post-Minskian. They understood Minsky's theory of bubbles and blow-outs, but believed that they could use it strategically for blowing bubbles, bursting them, and managing the fall-out by blowing some more.

 

Maximizing leverage

The process of arbitrage and bubble-blowing requires more of financial operators than simply bringing together the maximum amount of information about conditions across all markets; it also demands the capacity to mobilize huge funds to throw into any particular arbitrage play, in order to shift market dynamics in the speculator's favour.

 

A striking feature of the New Wall Street System business model was its relentless drive to expand balance sheets, maximizing the asset and liabilities sides. The investment banks used their leverage ratio as the target to be achieved at all times rather than as an outer limit of risk to be reduced where possible by holding surplus capital. A recent New York Federal Reserve report demonstrates how this approach proved powerfully pro-cyclical in an asset-market bubble, driving the banks to expand their borrowing as asset prices rose. [15] In their illustration, the report's authors, Tobias Adrian and Hyun Song Shin, assume that the bank actively manages its balance sheet to maintain a constant leverage ratio of 10. Suppose the initial balance sheet is as follows: the bank holds 100 worth of securities, and has funded this holding with an equity of 10, plus debt worth 90.

 

 

 

 

The bank's leverage ratio of security to equity is therefore 100/10 = 10.

 

Suppose the price of the securities then increases by 1 per cent, to 101. The proportions will then be: securities 101, equity 11, debt 90. So its leverage is now down to 101/11 = 9.2. If the bank still targets leverage of 10, then it must take on additional debt ('d'), to purchase d worth of securities on the asset side, so that the ratio of assets/equity is: (101+d)/11 = 10, i.e. d = 9.

 

The bank thus takes on additional debt worth 9, and with this money purchases securities worth 9. After the purchase, leverage is back up to 10. Thus, an increase in the price of the security of 1 leads to an increased holding worth 9: the demand curve is upward-sloping.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The mechanism works in reverse, too. Suppose there is shock to the securities price, so that the value of security holdings now falls to 109. On the liabilities side, it is equity that bears the burden of adjustment, since the value of debt stays approximately constant.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

But with securities at 109, equity at 10, debt at 99, leverage is now too high: 109/10 = 10.9.

 

The bank can adjust down its leverage by selling securities worth 9, and paying down 9 worth of debt. Thus, a fall in the price of securities leads to sales of securities: the supply curve is downward-sloping.

 

A central mechanism through which the investment banks could respond to asset-price rises was borrowing in the 'repurchase agreement'—or 'repo'—market. Typically, the investment bank wishes to buy a security, but needs to borrow funds to do so. On the settlement day, the bank receives the security, and then uses it as collateral for the loan needed to pay for it. At the same time, it promises the lender that it will repurchase the security at a given future date. In that way, the bank will repay the loan and receive the security. But typically, the funds for repurchasing the security from the lender are acquired by selling the security to someone else. Thus, on the settlement day, the original lender to the investment bank is paid off and hands over the security, which is immediately passed on to the new buyer in exchange for cash. This kind of repo funding operation presupposes an asset-price boom. It has accounted for 43 per cent of leverage growth amongst Wall Street banks, according to the same New York Fed report. Repos have also been the largest form of debt on investment banks' balance sheets in 2007–08. [16]

 

The question arises as to why the Wall Street banks (followed by others) pushed their borrowing to the leverage limit in such a systematic way. One explanation is that they were doing this in line with the wishes of their shareholders (once they had turned themselves into limited liability companies). 'Shareholder value' capitalism allegedly requires the ratio of assets to capital to be maximized. Surplus capital reduces the return on shareholder equity and acts as a drag on earnings per share. [17] But there is also another possible explanation for borrowing to the leverage limit: the struggle for market share and for maximum pricing power in trading activities. If you are a speculative arbitrageur or an asset-bubble blower, financial operational scale is essential to moving markets, by shifting prices in the direction you want them to go. In assessing which of these pressures—shareholder power or pricing power—drove the process, we should note how ready the Treasury, Fed and Wall Street executives have been to crush shareholder interests during the credit crunch, yet how resolutely they sought to protect the levels of leverage of the bulge-bracket banks during the bubble. By all accounts, Citigroup's turn to maximum balance-sheet and leverage expansion for trading activities derived not from shareholder pressure, but from the arrival there of Robert Rubin after his stint as us Treasury Secretary. [18]

 

Shadow banking

The drive for scale and for increasing leverage leads on to another basic feature of the New Wall Street System: the drive to create and expand a shadow-banking sector. Its most obvious features were the new, entirely unregulated banks, above all the hedge funds. These have had no specific functional role—they have simply been trader-banks free of any regulatory control or transparency in their speculative arbitrage. Private equity groups have also been, in essence, shadow trading banks, specializing in the buying and selling of companies. Special Investment Vehicles (sivs) and conduits are similarly part of this system. In the words of the director of regulation at Spain's central bank, these sivs and conduits 'were like banks but without capital or supervision'. Yet, as a Financial Times report noted: 'In the past two decades, most regulators have encouraged banks to shift assets off their balance sheets into sivs and conduits.' [19]

 

The shadow banking system was not in competition with the regulated system: it was an outgrowth of it. The regulated commercial and investment banks acted as the prime brokers of the shadow banking operators, thereby gaining very large profits from their activities. This increasingly central feature of official bank activity was, in reality, a way of massively expanding their balance sheets and leverage. To tap the Wall Street banks for funding, the hedge funds had to hand over collateral; but through a practice known as rehypothecation, a proportion of these collateral assets could then be used by the prime broker as its own collateral for raising itsown funds. The result was the self-financing of hugely profitable prime brokerage activities by the Wall Street banks, on a vast scale, without any extra commitment of their own capital: an ingenious way of greatly enlarging their leverage ratios. [20] The debate about whether deregulation or reregulation in the financial sector has been occurring since the 1980s seems to miss the point that there has been a combination of a regulated and an unregulated shadow system, working dynamically together.

 

Shadow banking refers not only to institutional agents, like hedge funds, but also to the practices and products which allowed the investment banks to expand their leverage. Since the late 1990s an increasingly important part of this side of shadow banking has been the 'over-the-counter' credit derivatives market, notably collateralized debt obligations (cdos) and credit default swaps (cdss). The most obvious attraction of these lay in the regulatory arbitrage they offered, enabling banks to expand leverage. [21] Traditionally banks had to insure their credit operations and such insurance entailed supplying collateral. The beauty of cdss lay in the fact that, as shadowy 'over-the-counter' products, they did not require the commitment of appropriate tranches of capital as collateral, and thus facilitated more leverage. cds expansion began on a major scale after derivatives specialists from jp Morgan Chase persuaded aig to start writing them on cdos in 1998. [22]

 

cdos were also a clever solution to leverage problems. By acquiring large quantities of securitized loans and thus greatly expanding their balance sheets, banks should have expanded their equity base. But cdos famously bundled together dozens or hundreds of such loans, of very varied quality, enabling the banks to increase their leverage. The cdos were typically written by the rating agencies, for a fee, and then given a Triple A rating by the same agency, for a second fee. Such ratings allowed the banks' equity commitments to be minimized. These securitized loans—mainly from the housing market, but also from credit-card debt and car loans—offered investors far higher rates of return than they could get in the money markets. The crucial point about these so-called 'structured securities' was not that they were securitized loans: these could in principle be perfectly safe; after all, a bond is, in reality, nothing but a securitized loan. But bonds have a clearly identifiable source, in an economic operator whose credit-worthiness and cash-flow capacities can be assessed; they also have clear prices in the secondary bond markets. The products bundled in cdos, however, came from hundreds of thousands of unidentifiable sources, whose credit-worthiness and cash-flow capacity was not known; they were sold 'over the counter', without any secondary market to determine prices, far less an organized market to minimize counterparty risk. In short, they were at best extremely risky because more or less totally opaque to those who bought them. At worst they proved a scam, so that within a few months of late 2007 the supposedly super-safe super-senior debt tranches within such cdos were being downgraded to junk status.

 

Leverage restrictions were also removed through public policy. Hank Paulson achieved a notable success in this area in 2004 when, as head of Goldman Sachs, he led the Wall Street campaign to get the Securities and Exchange Commission to agree to relax the so-called 'net capital rule', restricting leverage for large investment banks. Henceforth, firms were effectively allowed to decide their own leverage on the basis of their risk models. The result was a rapid rise in the big banks' leverage ratios. [23] Importantly it enabled them to transfer their capital base to new activities, such as collateralized debt obligations, which subsequently became such a significant element in their trading activities.

 

London's role

All these shifts are grouped under the euphemistic heading of 'financial innovation'—changes in institutional arrangements, products, oversight structures, enabling Wall Street banks to escape regulatory restrictions and expand their activities and profits. Dozens of shifts of this sort could be documented. But one of the most fundamental was the construction of a large, new shadow banking system in London, alongside the 'official' regulated sector. By the early 1990s the American investment banks had wiped out their London counterparts and dominated the Square Mile's asset markets, with the City acquiring an increasingly 'wimbledonized' role within the New Wall Street System. [24] Gordon Brown institutionalized the new relationship in 1997 by creating the unified Financial Services Authority, which claimed to operate according to 'principles' rather than binding rules: one central principle was that the Wall Street banks could regulate themselves. London thus became for New York something akin to what Guantánamo Bay would become for Washington: the place where you could do abroad what you could not do back home; in this instance, a location for regulatory arbitrage.

 

The term 'Wall Street' should therefore be understood to include London, as a satellite for these American operators. [25] Together London and New York dominate the issue of new shares and bonds. They are the centre of the foreign-exchange markets. Most significantly they have dominated the sale of over-the-counter derivatives, which make up the overwhelming bulk of derivatives sales. [26] In 2007, the uk had a global share of 42.5 per cent of derivatives based on interest rates and currencies, with the us handling 24 per cent. In terms of credit-derivatives trading, the us handled 40 per cent in 2006, while London handled 37 per cent (down from 51 per cent in 2002).

 

Funding speculation

The enormous expansion in the activities of the Wall Street banks and their shadow system required ever-larger amounts of funding. Such funding was classically supplied by the recycling of retail savings sitting in deposit accounts and, even more importantly, by the commercial banks creating large supplies of credit money. But in post-1980s America such retail savings were minuscule—a point to which we will return—and credit money from the commercial banks, though significant, was soon hopelessly inadequate. In these circumstances the trader banks turned to the wholesale money markets. At the heart of such markets were the inter-bank markets, with interest rates on, or just a few basis points above, the Fed's policy rates. Historically these markets were used to ensure that the banks were able to clear smoothly on a daily basis, rather than as a source of new, large-scale funding, let alone funding of a speculative nature. There was also the commercial-paper market, typically used by the big corporations for short-term funding, again principally to smooth their operations.

 

But in the New Wall Street System, these money markets were transformed. They remained centres of short-term lending, but they were increasingly funding speculative trading activity. On the supply side, the funds available for lending to Wall Street were expanding rapidly, especially through the expansion of pension funds during the 1980s and 1990s. In rather typical American style, a small change in the tax code through amendment 401K in 1980 opened the door to this development. This amendment gave a tax break to employees and employers if they put money into pension plans; the result was a massive flow of employee income into these plans, totalling nearly $400 billion by the end of the 1980s. By the late 1990s it had climbed to almost $2 trillion. [27]

 

At the same time as becoming key sources for the liabilities of the investment banks through short-term lending to them, the mutual funds, pension funds and so forth also became increasingly important targets for Wall Street's efforts to sell asset-backed securities, and in particular collateralized debt obligations. Thus the New Wall Street System attempted to draw the fund managers into speculative bubble activity on both the funding (liability) side and on the asset side, enabling ever-larger balance-sheet expansion.

 

ii. the causes of the crisis

It might, in principle, have been the case that the cluster of mutually re-inforcing innovations which we have called the New Wall Street System, were responses to the emergence of a housing-market bubble in the us from 2001. If so, we would have had a classic Minskian crisis linked to housing. In fact, all the key innovations were set in place before the onset of the bubble. Indeed there is ample evidence that the Wall Street banks quite deliberately planned a house-price bubble, and spent billions of dollars on advertising campaigns to persuade Americans to increase their mortgage-related debt. Citigroup ran a billion-dollar campaign with the theme 'Live Richly' in the 1990s, designed to get home owners to take out second mortgages to spend on whatever they liked. Other Wall Street banks acted in a similar fashion, with a great deal of success: debt in second mortgages climbed to over $1 trillion in a decade.

 

But the bubble that generated the credit crunch of 2007 lay not only—or even mainly—in the housing market, but in the financial system itself. The crisis was triggered not only by the scale of the debt bubble, but by its forms. In a normal over-lending crisis, when banks have ended up with non-performing loans (as in Japan in the 1990s), both the location and scale of the problems can be identified without much difficulty. But in 2007 the debt bubble within the financial system was concentrated in over-the-counter derivatives, in the form of individual cdos that had no market price or pricing mechanism—beyond the say-so of the ratings agencies—and which were distributed in their tens of thousands between the institutions at the summit of the financial system, as well as their satellite bodies such as sivs. Once this set of debt-accumulation arrangements was shown to be junk, in the two Paribas cases in August 2007, the suppliers of credit funding, such as money-market and pension funds, grasped that they had no way of knowing how much of the rest of the cdo mountain was also worthless. So they fled. Their refusal to keep supplying the handful of opaque Wall Street investment banks and their spin-offs with the necessary funds to keep the cdo market afloat was what produced the credit crunch.

 

The investment banks had initially spread the word that the effect of their securitization of debt had been to disperse risk widely across a multitude of bodies. But this seems to have been false: the Wall Street summit institutions themselves had been holding on to the so-called super-senior debt tranches, in tens of thousands of cdos. [28] They had been borrowing billions in the money markets to buy these instruments, gaining an interest rate on them some 10 basis points above their money-market borrowing costs. To continue to turn that profit they had to keep going back to the money markets to roll over their debts. Yet now the money markets were shutting down. [29] When investors in the money markets fled the recycling of short-term borrowing in the summer of 2007, the entire pyramid centred on the cdos began to crumble. When the Wall Street banks tried to off-load their cdos, they found there was no market for them. The insurance companies that had insured the cdos with cdss found their market collapsing, too.

 

Much remains obscure about the precise mechanisms through which the credit crunch acquired its scope and depth in 2007–08, mainly because the main Wall Street operators themselves sought to obfuscate both the nature of their plight and their survival tactics. But it is possible to trace a number of phases through which the crisis has passed. First, the attempt by the Fed and Treasury to defend the investment-bank model as the summit of the system, by acting as its lender of last resort. Second, with the fall of Lehman Brothers, the collapse of this effort and disappearance of the investment-bank model, producing a drive to consolidate a universal-bank model in which the trading activities of the investment banks would occur within, and protected by, the depository universal bank. In this phase, the Fed essentially substituted itself for the creditor institutions of the credit system, supplying loans, 'money-market' and 'commercial-paper market' funding for the banks. Between April and October 2008 this massive Central Bank funding operation involved about $5 trillion of credit from the Fed, the ecb and the Bank of England—equivalent to about 14 per cent of global gdp. Insofar as this state funding can continue without raising serious sovereign credit-worthiness problems, the most difficult and dangerous phase of the response to the crisis can get under way in a serious fashion. This will involve the deleveraging of the biggest banks, now in the context of negative feedback loops from deepening recessions. How and when this is achieved will give us a sense of the overall contours of the credit crunch.

 

Prevailing theories

Much of the mainstream debate on the causes of the crisis takes the form of an 'accidents' theory, explaining the debâcle as the result of contingent actions by, say, Greenspan's Federal Reserve, the banks, the regulators or the rating agencies. We have argued against this, proposing rather that a relatively coherent structure which we have called the New Wall Street System should be understood as having generated the crisis. But in addition to the argument above, we should note another striking feature of the last twenty years: the extraordinary harmony between Wall Street operators and Washington regulators. Typically in American history there have been phases of great tension, not only between Wall Street and Congress but also between Wall Street and the executive branch. This was true, for example, in much of the 1970s and early 1980s. Yet there has been a clear convergence over the last quarter of a century, the sign of a rather well-integrated project. [30]

 

An alternative explanation, much favoured in social-democratic circles, argues that both Wall Street and Washington were gripped by a false 'neo-liberal' or 'free-market' ideology, which led them astray. An ingenious right-wing twist on this suggests that the problematic ideology was 'laissez-faire'—that is, no regulation—while what is needed is 'free-market thinking', which implies some regulation. The consequence of either version is usually a rather rudderless discussion of 'how much' and 'what kind' of regulation would set matters straight. [31] The problem with this explanation is that, while the New Wall Street System was legitimated by free-market, laissez-faire or neo-liberal outlooks, these do not seem to have been operative ideologies for its practitioners, whether in Wall Street or in Washington. Philip Augar's detailed study of the Wall Street investment banks, The Greed Merchants, cited above, argues that they have actually operated in large part as a conscious cartel—the opposite of a free market. It is evident that neither Greenspan nor the bank chiefs believed in the serious version of this creed: neo-classical financial economics. Greenspan has not argued that financial markets are efficient or transparent; he has fully accepted that they can tend towards bubbles and blow-outs. He and his colleagues have been well aware of the risk of serious financial crisis, in which the American state would have to throw huge amounts of tax-payers' money into saving the system. They also grasped that all the various risk models used by the Wall Street banks were flawed, and were bound to be, since they presupposed a general context of financial market stability, within which one bank, in one market sector, might face a sudden threat; their solutions were in essence about diversification of risk across markets. The models therefore assumed away the systemic threat that Greenspan and others were well aware of: namely, a sudden negative turn across all markets. [32]

 

Greenspan's two main claims were rather different. The first was that, between blow-outs, the best way for the financial sector to make large amounts of money is to sweep away restrictions on what private actors get up to; a heavily regulated sector will make far less. This claim is surely true. His second claim has been that, when bubbles burst and blow-outs occur, the banks, strongly aided by the actions of the state authorities, can cope with the consequences. As William White of the bis has pointed out, this was also an article of faith for Bernanke. [33]

 

iii. systemic options

The real debate over the organization of financial systems in capitalist economies is not about methods and modes of regulation. It is a debate between systemic options, at two levels.

 

A public-utility credit and banking system, geared to capital accumulation in the productive sector versus a capitalist credit and banking system, subordinating all other economic activities to its own profit drives.

 

An international financial and monetary system under national-multilateral co-operative control versus a system of imperial character, dominated by the Atlantic banks and states working in tandem.

We can briefly look at each of these in turn.

 

A public-utility model?

All modern economic systems, capitalist or not, need credit institutions to smooth exchanges and transactions; they need banks to produce credit money and clearance systems to smooth the payment of debts. These are vital public services, like a health service. They are also inherently unstable: the essence of a bank, after all, is that it does not hold enough funds to cover all the claims of its depositors at any one time. Ensuring the safety of the system requires that competition between banks should be suppressed. Furthermore, policy questions as to where credit should be channelled are issues of great economic, social and political moment. Thus public ownership of the credit and banking system is rational and, indeed, necessary, along with democratic control. A public-utility model along these lines can, in principle, operate within capitalism. Even now the bulk of the German banking system remains in public hands, through savings banks and Landesbanken. The Chinese financial system is overwhelmingly centred on a handful of huge, publicly owned banks and the Chinese government does indeed steer the credit strategies of these banks. It is possible to envisage such a public-utility model operating with privatized banks. The post-war Japanese banking system could be held to have had this character, with all its banks strictly subordinated to the Bank of Japan's policy control via the 'window-guidance system'. The post-war British commercial bank cartel could also be viewed as broadly operating within that framework, albeit raking off excessive profits from its customers.

 

But a private capitalist credit system, centred on banks, would operate under the logic of money capital—in Marx's formula, m-m': advancing money to others to make more money. Once this principle is accepted as the alpha and omega of the banking system, the functional logic points towards the Greenspan apotheosis. This has been the model adopted in the us and the uk since the 1980s: making money-capital king. It entails the total subordination of the credit system's public functions to the self-expansion of money capital. Indeed, the entire spectrum of capitalist activity is drawn under the sway of money capital, in that the latter absorbs an expanding share of the profits generated across all other sectors. This has been the model that has risen to dominance as what we have called the New Wall Street System. It has been a generator of extraordinary wealth within the financial system and has actually transformed the process of class formation in the Anglo-Saxon economies. This model is now in deep crisis.

 

The second debate centres around the underwriting of financial systems. Whether public or private, banking and credit systems are inherently unstable in any system where output is validated after production, in the market-place. [34] In such circumstances, these systems must be underwritten and controlled by public authorities with tax-raising capacities and currency-printing presses. Insofar as they are minimally public bodies—not utterly captured by the private interests of money capital—these authorities will aim to prevent crises by trying to bring the behaviour of the financial system roughly into line with broad (micro as well as macro) economic goals. At present, only states have the capacity to play this role. Rule books like Basel I or II cannot do it; neither can the eu Commission or the ecb.

 

Intriguingly, the Atlantic projects grouped under the name of 'economic globalization'—the fiat dollar system, ending of capital controls, free entry and exit of big Atlantic operators in other financial systems—have ensured that most states have been deprived of the capacity to underwrite and control their own financial systems: hence the endless financial blow-outs in the South over the last thirty years. Atlantic business interests benefited from these crises, not only because their losses were fully covered by imf insurance—paid for later by poor people in the countries hit—but also because they were used as occasions to sweep open the product and labour markets of these countries to Atlantic penetration. But now the blow-outs have hit the metropolitan heartland itself. Obviously the Atlantic economies will want to keep this system going: the practices covered by 'financial globalization' constitute their most profitable export sector. But it is not so clear that the rest of the world will buy a formula for more of the same. The alternative would be some return to public control, along with public underwriting. This could only be achieved by individual national states regaining effective control, via new multilateral co-operative systems comparable to those that existed before 1971, implemented on a regional if not fully international scale.

 

Here, however, we will focus on the question of why the financial model centred on the New Wall Street System has achieved such complete hegemony within American capitalism over the past few decades. This takes us, finally, back out of the financial sphere into the wider field of socio-economic and socio-political relations in the us since the 1970s. Within this broader context, we can begin to understand how the New Wall Street System's rise to dominance within the us could have been seen as a strategic idea for tackling the problems of the American economy.

 

Financial dominance as national strategy

From the 1970s through to the early 1980s, the American state waged a vigorous battle to revive the industrial economy, partly through a mercantilist turn in external trade policy, but above all through a domestic confrontation with labour to reduce its share of national income. This was the vision of such leaders as Paul Volcker; it was assumed that these measures would return American industry to world dominance. Yet the hoped-for broad-based industrial revival did not take place. By the mid-1980s, non-financial corporate America was falling under the sway of short-term financial engineering tactics, geared towards the goal of enhancing immediate 'shareholder value'. What followed was wave after wave of mergers and acquisitions and buy-outs by financial operators, encouraged by Wall Street investment banks who profited handsomely from such operations. The legitimating argument that this was 'enhancing industrial efficiency' seems scarcely credible. A more convincing case would be that these trends were driven by the new centrality of the financial sector within the structure of American capitalism. [35]

 

A full explanation of this development is, I think, not yet available. But the trend produced some structural features of American capitalism that have been present ever since. On the one hand, a protected military-industrial sector remains intact, funded from federal and state budgets. Some high-tech sectors, especially in ict, were also strongly supported by state subsidies in the 1980s and 90s, and have involved real new industrial investment, without as yet playing a transformative role in the overall economy: the main impact of ict has been in the financial sector and retail. But the bulk of the American economy, on which growth depends, has been marked by stagnant or even declining incomes amongst the mass of the population and no growth motor from new investment, whether public or private. With the partial exception of ict investment in the late 90s, gdp growth in the us has not been driven by new investment at all. As is widely recognized, it has come to depend upon the stimulus of consumer demand; yet such household consumption was itself inhibited by stagnant mass incomes.

 

This circle was famously squared in two ways. First and most important, the problem of stimulating consumer demand was tackled through the sustained supply of credit from the financial system. Secondly, cheap commodities could be bought on an endless basis from abroad—especially from China—since dollar dominance enabled the us to run up huge current-account deficits, as other countries allowed their exports to the us to be paid for in dollars. The supply of credit from the financial system to the mass of consumers through the usual mechanisms of credit card, car debt and other loans and mortgages was, however, supplemented by the distinctive mechanism of asset-price bubbles, which generated so-called wealth effects among a relatively broad layer. The stock-market bubble of the 1990s raised the paper value of the private pensions of the mass of Americans, thus giving them a sense that they were becoming richer and could spend (and indebt themselves) more. The housing bubble had a double effect: it not only made American consumers feel confident that the value of their house was rising, enabling them to spend more; it was reinforced by a strong campaign from the banks, as we have seen, urging them to take out second mortgages and use the new money for consumption spending.

 

Thus the New Wall Street System directly fuelled the 1995–2008 consumer-led American boom, which ensured that the us continued to be the major driver of the world economy. This was backed by a global campaign to the effect that the us boom was not the result of debt-fed growth aided by highly destructive trends in the financial system, but of American free-market institutions. Here, then, was the basis in the broader social relations of American capitalism for the rise to dominance of the New Wall Street System: it played the central role in ensuring debt-fed growth. This Anglo-Saxon model was based upon the accumulation of consumer debt: it was growth today, paid for by hoped-for growth tomorrow. It was not based upon strengthening the means of value-generation in the economies concerned. In short, it was a bluff, buttressed by some creative national accounting practices which exaggerated the extent of the American boom and productivity gains in the us economy. [36]

 

The role of China and other Asian exporting economies in this growth model extended beyond their large export surpluses of consumer goods to the us. These export surpluses were recycled back into the American financial system via the purchasing of us financial assets, thus cheapening the costs of debt by massively expanding 'liquidity' within the financial system. The results of these trends can be summarized in the following figures. Aggregate us debt as a percentage of gdp rose from 163 per cent in 1980 to 346 per cent in 2007. The two sectors which account for this rise were household debt and internal financial-sector debt. Household debt rose from 50 per cent of gdp in 1980 to 100 per cent of gdp in 2007. But the really dramatic rise in indebtedness occurred within the financial sector itself: from 21 per cent of gdp in 1980 to 83 per cent in 2000 and 116 per cent in 2007. [37]

 

iv. implications

The ideological effects of the crisis will be significant, though of course far less significant than imagined by those who believe financial regimes are the product of intellectual paradigms rather than power relations. Yet the cant dished out in the past by the us Treasury and imf is over. American-style financial-system models are now grasped as being dangerous. No less risky is the eu banking and financial-system framework, which the crisis has shown to be a house of cards, even if still standing at the time of writing. The eu's guiding notion is that banking systems are secured by good rules rather than by authoritative states with tax-raising powers. This has been shown to be a dangerous joke. The whole eu–emu project has encouraged banks to grow too big for their national states to save them, while offering no alternative at eu or even Eurozone level. Absurdly, the Single Market and Competition rules in the financial sector insist on free competition between banks at all costs, and proscribe any state aid for them; while if the stability criteria were respected, any full-blown credit crisis would necessarily be transformed into a 1930s-style depression. Obviously these rules are for the birds, yet they are simultaneously the principal planks of the eu political economy. [38]

 

This crisis of the American and European set-ups will no doubt have two intellectual effects. Firstly, to raise the credibility of the Chinese model of a state-owned, bank-centred financial system. This is the serious alternative to the credit models of the Atlantic world. The maintenance of capital controls and a non-convertible currency—which China has—are essential for the security of this system. Secondly, as the crisis unfolds, broader discussion of the public-utility model seems likely to return to political life, re-opening a debate that has been silenced since 1991.

 

Some predict much more sweeping short-term changes, such as the replacement of the dollar as the global currency or the collapse of Western leadership institutions within the world economy. A complete debauching of the dollar by the Obama Administration could, perhaps, lead to a stampede to dump it globally, along with a retreat into regional or narrow imperial trading blocs. [39] But no less likely could be a temporary strengthening of the use of the dollar over the next decade: a long stagnation in the us may well be combined with very low interest rates and a low dollar. This could produce a new dollar carry trade, in which everybody borrows in dollars to take them across the exchanges into higher value assets. This would produce a strong trend towards a decoupling of other exchange rates from the dollar, but it would not necessarily undermine the central element in dollar dominance: the readiness of other states to accept payments for their goods and credits in greenbacks.

 

We are also likely to see the intensification of the two basic structural trends in long-term credit-debt relations in the world economy. First, the creditor relations between the Atlantic world and its traditional South in Latin America, Africa and elsewhere, historically policed by the imf. This relationship weakened over the last decade but is likely to be re-inforced in the present crisis. Second, the contrary debtor relations between the United States and the East Asian New Growth Centre economies, which are also likely to deepen and tighten, particularly between China and the us. This is a power relationship in which China (and other creditors) can exercise real political leverage over Washington. We have seen this operating in both the timing and the form of the renationalization of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac. [40] We will see it again as the us Treasury seeks buyers of its large new tranches of debt in 2009. The East Asian economies, above all China, will likely become ever more critical to global macro-economic trends, while the erstwhile centrality of the us will weaken during its long stagnation. The strengthened financial clout of China and other East Asian states could impinge upon the old imperial credit-debt relationships between the Atlantic world and the South, by offering the latter alternative sources of financial support. This threat is already prompting warnings in the Atlantic world for Washington to soften the predatory conditions it has traditionally imposed on Africa, Latin America and elsewhere. [41]

 

But whether this will mean that East Asia will start to build new market institutional arrangements for the world economy, challenging those of the Anglo-American world, remains unclear, for two reasons: first, the internal divisions within East Asia; and second, the question of China's strategic priorities at the present time. Thus, East Asia has an obvious rational collective interest in building its own, centralized commodity and oil markets and promoting them to world leadership, ending the dominance of London and Chicago. Such new market frameworks have sprung up, but they are divided: one in Hong Kong, one in Japan and one in Singapore. As for China, it is currently overwhelmingly concentrated on maintaining domestic growth and carrying through the leap of dynamic capital accumulation from the coast to the interior. At present, it is showing not the slightest interest in challenging the Americans for leadership in shaping the institutions of the world economy. Thus the us has some breathing space. But such is the social and political strength of Wall Street, and the weakness of social forces that might push for an industrial revival there, that it would seem most likely that the American capitalist class will squander its chance. If so, it will enjoy another round of debt-fed gdp growth funded by China and others while the us becomes ever less central to the world economy, ever less able to shape its rules and increasingly caught in long-term debt subordination to the East Asian credit matrix.

 

 

--------------------------------------------------------------------------------

 

[1] Leslie Crawford and Gillian Tett, 'Spain spared because it learnt lesson the hard way', Financial Times, 5 February 2008.

[2] The total debt owed by financial and non-financial private sectors in the us in 2008 has been calculated at $48 trillion. George Magnus, 'Important to curb destructive power of deleveraging', ft, 30 September 2008.

[3] David Patterson, 'Central Banks must find or become buyers of system risk', ft, 5 February 2008.

[4] For a useful survey of why most economists were completely incapable of grasping the crisis, see Chris Giles, 'The Vision Thing', ft, 26 November 2008.

[5] Javier Blas, 'Commodities have proved a saving grace for investors', ft, 6 March 2008; Chris Flood, 'Speculators give a stir to coffee and cocoa prices' ft, 5 February 2008. That these financial operators were able to build and burst such bubbles derived, of course, from the fact that the markets for oil and commodities are organized in London, New York and Chicago, with rules made to match the interests of American and British capital. As Jeff Sprecher, ceo of Intercontinental Exchange (ice), the London-based market whose rules enabled blowing the oil bubble, explained to the Financial Times, the market's organizers could not understand why members of Congress should want to give up control over this sector by closing ice down. 'View from the Top', ft, 6 August 2008.

[6] Lawrence Summers, 'The pendulum swings towards regulation', ft, 27 October 2008. The figure of 40 per cent actually understates the share of profits accruing to the financial sector, since these are in part concealed by being transformed into huge employee bonuses, to reduce headline profits data; one reason for the bonus system that is often overlooked.

[7] For an earlier exploration of these issues see my Global Gamble, New York and London 1999.

[8] The bread-and-butter of Wall Street investment bank income had been fixed (cartelized) fees for trading securities on behalf of clients until 1975, when a change in the law limited such fees. At the start of the 1980s, this fee income was still greater for the investment banks than profits from trading on their own account. But from the mid-1980s, these banks plunged seriously into proprietary trading. By the end of the 1990s, trading income was a third bigger than income from commissions for trading on behalf of others. And some of the biggest banks earned over half their profits from such trading. See John Gapper, 'The last gasp of the broker-dealer', ft, 16 September 2008.

[9] On Salomon Brothers and the subsequent career of John Meriwether's team in the 1990s, when they constructed ltcm under the sponsorship of Merrill Lynch, see Roger Lowenstein, When Genius Failed, London 2001.

[10] After the Enron scandal, sivs and conduits were initially not allowed to engage in active trading on their own account, but this restriction was soon lifted.

[11] James Mackintosh, 'Collapse of Lehman leaves prime broker model in question', ft, 25 September 2008.

[12] Philip Augar gives a vivid account of how key such informational centralization from all the main markets was in giving the investment banks a decisive competitive edge over their smaller or non-investment banking rivals. See his The Greed Merchants: How the Investment Banks Played the Free Market Game, London 2006.

[13] See Nasser Saber, Speculative Capital: The Invisible Hand of Global Finance, London 1999.

[14] Alan Greenspan, 'We will never have a perfect model of risk', ft, 17 March 2008.

[15] Tobias Adrian and Hyun Song Shin, 'Liquidity and Leverage', Staff Report no. 328, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, May 2008. The term 'leverage' refers to the relationship between a bank's 'equity' or 'capital' and its assets—the sum that it has lent out. It is usually expressed as a ratio, so that if we say that Lehman's leverage at the time of its collapse was 25, this means that for every one dollar of capital the bank had 25 dollars of assets. But this figure of 25 also means that for every one dollar of capital, Lehman had 24 dollars worth of borrowings—i.e. liabilities.

[16] Adrian and Song Shin, 'Liquidity and Leverage'.

[17] The rewards of senior bank executives were often linked to changing earnings per share. See John Kay, 'Surplus capital is not for wimps after all', ft, 22 October 2008.

[18] See, among others, 'Singing the blues', Economist, 27 November 2008.

[19] Leslie Crawford and Gillian Tett, 'Spain spared because it learnt lesson the hard way', ft, 5 February 2008.

[20] James Mackintosh, 'Collapse of Lehman leaves prime broker model in question', ft, 25 September 2008.

[21] Christina Bannier and Dennis Hänsel, 'Determinants of European Banks' Engagement in Loan Securitization', Deutsche Bundesbank Discussion Paper Series 2: Banking and Financial Studies no. 10/2008.

[22] Gretchen Morgenson, 'Behind crisis at aig, a fragile web of risks. Tiny London unit set decline in motion', International Herald Tribune, 29 September 2008.

[23] Stephen Labaton, 'How sec opened path for storm in 55 minutes', International Herald Tribune, 4/5 October 2008. In a classic manoeuvre, this was dressed up as a turn by the sec towards more regulation of the investment banks. From a formal point of view this was right: the sec acquired regulatory jurisdiction over them; but it simultaneously removed basic capital-base restrictions. Furthermore, from 2004 onwards the sec had seven staff to supervise the big five investment banks, which had combined assets of over $4 trillion by 2007.

[24] The annual tennis tournament in Wimbledon is widely considered, at least in the uk, to be the greatest in the world; yet for decades there has been no British finalist.

[25] There are some very large British commercial banks, but these should be distinguished from the City of London because, while some have participated heavily in the New Wall Street System, others such as the Hongkong and Shanghai Banking Corporation (hsbc), by some measures the largest bank in the world, and the Standard Chartered Bank, have been heavily focused on activities in East Asia.

[26] The Chicago Mercantile Exchange, however, dominates sales of exchange-traded derivatives.

[27] Roger Lowenstein, Origins of the Crash, New York 2004, pp. 24–5. This expansion of bank funding for speculative trading through the transformation of the 'wholesale' markets intersected, of course, with the ending of capital controls, enabling the growth of international wholesale borrowing by banks and the rise of 'carry trade' operations, such as that based on the yen: banks borrowing in yen, at 0.5 per cent or less, and taking the funds into the Icelandic krona, at 18 per cent. The funding of British commercial banks, overwhelmingly domestic at the start of the 1990s, had become largely based on overseas wholesale lending, to the tune of about £650bn, by 2007.

[28] Gillian Tett, 'Misplaced bets on the carry trade', ft, 17 April 2008.

[29] For a useful mainstream (and apologetic) account of the risks involved in cdos and over-the-counter derivatives like cdss, see the imf publication by Garry Schinasi, Safeguarding Financial Stability: Theory and Practice, Washington, dc 2006.

[30] There were tensions between Wall Street and New York state regulator Eliot Spitzer after the dot.com bubble burst, but this simply highlighted how strong was the consensus at a higher level.

[31] References to these kinds of debates can be found in Andrew Baker et al., Governing Financial Globalization, London 2005.

[32] See Greenspan, 'We will never have a perfect model of risk'; Alan Beattie and James Politi, 'Greenspan admits he made a mistake', ft, 24 October 2008.

[33] Cited in John Cassidy, 'Anatomy of a Meltdown: Ben Bernanke and the Financial Crisis', New Yorker, 1 December 2008.

[34] Though this does not mean that they are all equally unstable.

[35] This is not to say that American industrial production disappeared: it remained large, notably in the defence-budget related sector as well as in cars, aerospace, ict and pharmaceuticals.

[36] A series of changes in us national accounting rules from 1995 onwards exaggerated both growth and productivity figures. Notable here was the use of so-called 'hedonic indicators'.

[37] Martin Wolf, 'Why Paulson's Plan was not a true solution to the crisis', ft, 24 September 2008.

[38] In addition, Western eu states made an unstated but real precondition for Eastern enlargement that the new entrants hand over the bulk of their commercial banks to their Western counterparts; a remarkable imperial move. These Western banks will now wish to starve the Eastern eu members of credit, as they seek every trick to deleverage and survive. Will the eu political authorities intervene in the market to block this? If so, how?

[39] A trend in this direction is evident in the us decision to give special treatment to Mexico, Brazil, Singapore and South Korea in terms of dollar-funding support.

[40] The Financial Times reported that us Treasury Secretary Paulson confronted the fact that 'the Bank of China had cut its exposure to agency debt over the summer' and thus: 'found himself with a fait accompli. The federal government had to give reassurance to foreign investors in agency debt if it wanted to avoid chaos in financial markets and a run on the dollar. It smacks of debt crises past in Latin American countries, where the ultimate pressure for a bail-out came from foreign investors.' John Gapper, 'A us government bail-out of foreign investors', ft, 8 September 2008.

[41] David Rothkopf, 'The Fund faces up to competition', ft, 22 October 2008.


 



__._,_.___


[Disclaimer: ALOCHONA Management is not liable for information contained in this message. The author takes full responsibility.]
To unsubscribe/subscribe, send request to alochona-owner@egroups.com




Your email settings: Individual Email|Traditional
Change settings via the Web (Yahoo! ID required)
Change settings via email: Switch delivery to Daily Digest | Switch to Fully Featured
Visit Your Group | Yahoo! Groups Terms of Use | Unsubscribe

__,_._,___